Solving the Syrian riddle

April 1st, 2013

Published on openDemocrazy, by JIHAD YAZIGI, March 26, 2013.

The only Arab country where protests started from rural areas might find itself facing an internationally funded reconstruction which will award money to urban centres, thus abandoning the very roots of the current crisis. The only solution is to build economic awareness. Starting from now.  

One just has to look at the geography of how events evolved in Syria, the locations where demonstrations started, the places where people took to the streets, to realize that, at heart, this revolt started from rural areas, whether it was from the countryside or the suburban peripheries outside Damascus and Aleppo.

This beckons us to question ourselves over the economic roots of the current upraising. After all, the business classes of inner Damascus and Aleppo were initially in support – or, when not in support, at least tacitly affirmative -  of keeping the status quo. Joining the opposition was simply not in their interests … //

… The Syrian opposition:

  • This happened in a country where the state had supported agriculture and represented the farmer’s interests for 40 years, and where bread and electricity were still subsidized by the Government. Today, it is all reflected in the current outline of the Syrian opposition, where the first ones to revolt are the farmers and the inhabitants of the poverty belts outside major cities.
  • Traditionally, this is not a class represented by the Muslim Brotherhood. The brotherhood is generally known to cater for the former landowners reaching into the city, the engineers and doctors, in a word, the brotherhood is traditionally an urban phenomenon. It is then inevitable to pose the question of whose interests are going to be represented by future economic policies in a post-conflict Syria.
  • And while the class dimension is only one of the different factors that need to be taken into consideration when looking at events which unfolded against a dictatorship, and which see also political activists and freedom demands being advanced, the economic roots of this revolt need to be taken into consideration starting from now by opposition groups, which are still partly unaware of this problematic.
  • Because all this is clearly reflected within the current Syrian uprising and its social components, and proves how politically decisive it will be to have a clear economic plan in mind once – in six month, a year, two years – this conflict is over and probably Qatari or Saudi money could prove to be more powerful than any political economy discussion, if there is no plan ready.

Solutions that take time: … //

… Some things that won’t work:

  • The risk is that a post-conflict scenario will see international aid heading towards the main urban areas, replicating the regime’s neglect of a larger rural reality – which was the first one to take to the streets.
  • If there are chances of reconstruction funding to come, I do not expect an influx of western money coming into Syria, because the USA and the EU are clearly facing other problems at the moment. Should the present conflict end with a clear defeat of the Assad regime, it is in fact more likely that Gulf countries will be more interested in having a political grip over Syria. And in my opinion, this is how capital and investments will come in.
  • But these are countries looking for new markets while, at the same time, traditionally investing in real estate, finance and hospitality. Despite real estate reconstruction being an urgent problem, given the level of destruction and death Syria has faced, the future leadership will need to keep in mind a priority on working to create long-term employment by investing in agriculture and factories, which is in fact unlikely to happen if you depend on Gulf money.
  • To this, one must add a political problem: Gulf countries, especially Qatar but also Saudi Arabia, rely heavily on state money. The scenario, in this case, is State-to-State aid.  But Syria, unlike Gulf countries, cannot become a rent economy; nor we can afford the geo-political dependence that such an exclusively State-to-State plan would entail.
  • It is clear that diversification of the sources of reconstruction funding, and therefore a carefully thought economic policy, will be key to the future of post-conflict Syria. The new leadership will have to look for various different alternatives other than just Qatari and Saudi money, taking into account the different political economies they imply.
  • And in this case it is probably Turkey that will have a crucial role to play in creating long-term added value – in a word, durable jobs in productive sectors. Turkey is not a rent economy, and what we will probably have is private Turkish enterprises investing in Syria because costs are competitive.
  • Our understanding of the Syrian economy must take all this into consideration starting from now. Because when Syria will finally emerge from this conflict, when the choice will be between bad and very bad, it will be too late to consider. We must be aware of Syrian contradictions, and prepare ourselves to adapt our policies to what will be realistic on the ground.

(full text).

Links:

on Current Concerns no 13, March 28, 2013: The Nato-aggression against Yugoslavia from 1999:

Comments are closed.